人妻少妇专区

Please consider

In Review

NOBEL PRIZESA Conversation with Rochester鈥檚 Latest Nobel Prize Recipient Richard Thaler 鈥74 (PhD) talks about counting cashews, a life-changing scientific paper, why people don鈥檛 behave rationally with money, and鈥攐h, yes鈥攔eceiving a Nobel Prize. Interview by Sandra Knispel
thalerFOUNDING FIGURE: Widely recognized as a founding figure in a field that argues traditional economic models don鈥檛 adequately account for how people approach economic decisions, Thaler is a leading scholar on the intersection between human behavior and economic decision making. (Photo: Scott Olson/Getty Images)

Richard Thaler, the Charles R. Walgreen Distinguished Service Professor of Economics and Behavioral Science at the University of Chicago鈥檚 Booth School of Business, has a prized item at a store in Chicago, waiting to be framed.

Special University Guest

The University awarded Thaler an honoray degree during commencement ceremonies in 2010. He also was a panelist for a conversation on the “The Future of Financial Regulation” during Meliora Weekend in 2009. As part of that year’s Presidential Symposium, he was joined by then SEC chair Mary Shapiro, then Goldman Sachs managing director E. Gerald Corrigan, and former SEC chair Richard Breeden. The conversation was moderated by University Trustee Hugo Sonnenschein 鈥61.

It鈥檚 鈥渢he best thing that has happened so far,鈥 he says about the aftermath of winning the 2017 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences this fall. It鈥檚 a congratulatory letter from former President Barack Obama, a fellow Nobel laureate and erstwhile Chicago faculty member. 鈥淭hat was very thoughtful of him,鈥 says Thaler, who earned his PhD at Rochester in 1974, and taught at the University until 1978.

The Nobel committee recognized Thaler for his contributions to behavioral economics, a field that he helped create, one that bridges the gap between economics and psychology. At its core is the premise that people often behave in human ways, rather than in ways that are more rational and selfish, which had been the standard economic assumption.

Rochester鈥檚 Nobel Laureates

Economist Richard Thaler 鈥74 (PhD) became Rochester鈥檚 ninth Nobel Prize recipient this fall, when he was recognized for his work in behavioral economics. He joins five other graduates and three faculty members among the University鈥檚 Nobel laureates.

2002 Nobel Prize in Physics

Physicist Masatoshi Koshiba 鈥55 (PhD), who led work to detect the subatomic particles known as neutrinos.

1997 Nobel Prize in Physics

Physicist Steven Chu 鈥70, former Secretary of Energy, who developed methods to cool and trap atoms with laser light.

1993 Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences

Economist Robert Fogel, a former faculty member who pioneered quantitative analyses of social history.

1976 Nobel Prize in Physiology or Medicine

Carleton Gajdusek 鈥43, who is credited with discovering the infectious disease mechanism of prions.

1959 Nobel Prize in Physiology or Medicine

Arthur Kornberg 鈥41M (MD), who first discovered a way to synthesize DNA.

1955 Nobel Prize in Chemistry

Vincent du Vigneaud 鈥27 (PhD), a biochemist, for research on sulfur-containing compounds.

1943 Nobel Prize in Physiology or Medicine

Biochemist Henrick Dam for his discovery of vitamin K.

1934 Nobel Prize in Physiology or Medicine

George Whipple, founding dean of the School of Medicine and Dentistry, for his work to develop a therapy for anemia.

How did he get there? Well, cashews played a part. At a Rochester dinner party, he and his fellow graduate students were eating cashews too quickly. He called that a problem of self-control and ultimately short-sightedness, especially if you can鈥檛 stop eating cashews while knowing that dinner is just around the corner. He told the New York Times that if 鈥渢he cashews aren鈥檛 in front of you, you鈥檙e less tempted to eat them. In fact, if you have to get up and walk all the way to the kitchen鈥攜ou don鈥檛 end up eating so much.鈥

It鈥檚 such daily insights that spurred his intellectual curiosity.

Thaler has made a name for himself by studying why people predictably don鈥檛 act the way traditional economists say they will. Predictably, that has pitted him against fellow economists.

Known for his sharp wit, he told NPR in 2015 that economists have devoted themselves to studying fictional creatures by assuming that people 鈥渁re highly rational creatures capable of complex calculations, devoid of emotion, never having any self-control problems, and they鈥檙e complete jerks.鈥

The sixth alumnus to receive the prize, Thaler is Rochester鈥檚 ninth Nobel laureate and the second in economics after former faculty member Robert Fogel, one of Thaler鈥檚 teachers.

You鈥檝e said that for the last 50 or 60 years, economists have devoted themselves to studying fictional creatures. 鈥淭hey might as well be studying unicorns,鈥 you said. That must have really endeared you to fellow economists.

Yes, it did not go over well at the Simon School where I was teaching, so I had to leave Rochester for Cornell. I told people I was moving south for the weather.

Where was that 鈥済igantic house in Rochester鈥 where you left the cashews in the kitchen so as to reduce your and your fellow graduate students鈥 consumption?

It was certainly not a gigantic house. Probably graduate student housing. Later I lived on Stanford Road near the hospital.

Do you have more friends in the field now that you won the Nobel Prize?

No, but I have heard from many old friends, even some from childhood. That has been great fun. But the best thing that has happened so far is getting a personal note from President Obama. That was very thoughtful of him.

You joked that you would spend the 9 million Swedish krona prize money as irrationally as possible and called it 鈥渇un money.鈥 Have you started? On what?

Well, I haven鈥檛 gotten the money yet, so according to behavioral economics I will not start splurging until I get the money. I have bought plane tickets for my kids and their spouses to join the festivities in Stockholm, but that is highly rational.

What were you obsessed with in Rochester when you worked on your PhD here? Besides cashews and garbage plates鈥攊ntellectually, I mean?

My PhD thesis, supervised by Sherwin Rosen [the late Rochester labor economist], was on the value of a human life. It was a very standard economic exercise, estimating how much you had to pay people to take risky jobs, but I did ask some questions that piqued my interest. I asked people how much they would pay to eliminate a 1/1000th risk of death and how much they would have to be paid to accept an increased risk of death of 1/1000th. The answers differed wildly, often by several orders of magnitude. Standard economic theory said they should be about the same. That got me thinking deviant thoughts.

During that time you read a paper that had just been published by psychologists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky鈥斺淛udgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases.鈥 This one paper altered the course of your work, your life . . . how?

They had one key idea that made my research possible, namely that people made predictable errors in judgments.

Economists were happy to admit that people made mistakes but they thought the mistakes would just wash out and add random noise. The idea of systematic bias was fundamental.

You came up with the idea of sunk costs because of a snow storm in Buffalo . . .

Economists are always telling people to ignore 鈥渟unk costs,鈥 that is, money that has already been spent. They also assume that people naturally behave as if they understood this concept, even though they have trouble teaching it to students.

The story you are referring to was this: a friend and I were given two tickets to an NBA game in Buffalo back when they had a team. There was a big snow storm so we didn鈥檛 go, but my non-economist friend said, 鈥淚f we had paid for those tickets we would have gone for sure.鈥 I thought, 鈥淗mmm, another item for my list of funny behavior.鈥

May we call you the father of behavioral economics? When did you realize that you were on to something that would either shake up your field or make you a total outcast?

Some have called me that, though the field has many creators. And yes, it did make me an outcast in some places, including Rochester. I think that will still be the case now at the Simon School.

In your latest book Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioral Economics (W. W. Norton, 2016), you tell stories of things that people do that don鈥檛 make sense in traditional economic theory. Is most of the traditional theory rubbish?

No, economic theory is not rubbish. In fact, it is essential to what I do. But economic theory is about how people 鈥渟hould鈥 behave if they want to be rational. We need that theory, but we also need other theories to say how people actually behave.

In return, a colleague accused you in 2004 of being a 鈥減aternalist鈥濃攈ave you made peace with that title? Or is 鈥減rofessional nudge鈥 better?

My colleague and I call it libertarian paternalism because it is true that we are trying to help people (the paternalistic part), but we try to do so without requiring anyone to do anything (the libertarian part). That is what our book Nudge [written with Harvard Law School Professor Cass Sunstein] is about.

Have you finished writing your acceptance speech for the Swedish Academy? Want to give us a preview sentence or two? Will the word 鈥渆nh枚rning鈥 (Swedish for unicorn) come up?

No, haven鈥檛 started. Too busy answering interviews like this one. Now back to work!